ARE 132: COOPERATIVE
BUSINESS ENTERPRISES
Prof. Kiesel
Allocation of Losses
Like IOFs, cooperatives sometimes incur
operating losses
Too many years of losses can force a co-op
to become bankrupt
Ways to allocate losses
Charge against past allocated equity
Charge against unallocated equity (most
common)
Cash collection (send bills—very rare)
Co-op Member Payment
Methods
Members of supply & retail
cooperatives usually receive refund
checks after fiscal year closing
Members of marketing cooperatives are
also paid for delivering raw product to
the cooperative, which processes and
markets it
Various ways that members of marketing
co-ops can be paid for their deliveries
Co-op Member Payment
Method: $ on Delivery
Many co-ops, especially grain & oilseed co-
ops, pay cash for commodities on delivery
Raw product is then processed & sold
Net income remaining after expenses is
refunded to members
Provides immediate cash payment to
members
Co-op takes title & assumes risk
Commercial Market Value
(CMV)
Approximates price paid if commodity sold
directly to Investor Owned Firm (IOF)
Relatively common for fruit & veg marketing
co-ops
Some cooperatives will pay CMV upon
delivery
CMV is reported as part of “cost of goods sold”
and/or used to compare with co-op’s return
When crop is processed & gets sold out, net
income determined & patronage return paid
Back to Economic Theory
Paid as if price taker and selling to IOF firm
Usually maximizes member delivery payment
Usually minimizes co-op net income &
patronage returns--close to breakeven pricing
Requires co-op to have significant operating
capital
Puts co-op at risk for losses
Commercial Market Value
(CMV) (Cont.)
Key Concepts: Marketing
Margin
Marketing margin will typically include the costs of the
following:
Assembly of the raw products from the farm
Processing
Distribution
Retailing
Alternatively, break margin down into costs for inputs (e.g.
labor, capital, energy, materials, etc.) and mark up
𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡∗ = (𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟 -M)/K
𝑃𝑃𝑡𝑡∗ as maximum farm price
𝑃𝑃𝑟𝑟 as retail price
M as margin
K as conversion factor
1. Margin Reduction
Two possible ways to lower margin:
1. Cooperative might face lower prices for some
inputs used in marketing
2. Cooperative might market the product more
efficiently than presently done
Three advantages of internalizing transactions
1. Internalization creates common incentive
among parties
2. Disputes within organizations can be
resolved quickly
3. Information flows more freely
2. Market Power Avoidance
Opportunistic behavior results in trading partners
attempting to exercise short-term market power
over farms
Monopsony power
Monopoly power
Oligopoly power
Price discrimination
Potential leverage exercised by bargaining associations
(e.g. Cooperatives):
1. Play marketing firms off against each other, causing them
to bid up prices
2. Threaten to withhold product from private handler by
forming cooperative to directly process and sell product
3. Influence Consumer Prices
Two possible avenues:
1. Cooperative might be able to restrict flow of farm
product to the market
2. Cooperative might be able to improve quality of the
finished product or offer value-added products
Oversupply(relative to demand) at heart of American
agriculture’s financial dilemma in many markets
Demand to
Wholesaler
MR to Wholesaler
Double - Marginalization
Marketing Year
Agricultural crops processed as
inputs/ingredients for (food) products
Value of crop not known at harvest but
becomes known after product sold to
consumer (before new harvest)
12 month period (often begins Sept 1 and
ends Aug 31)
Advance payment at harvest
Second payment as value becomes known
(4-6 month)
Final payment at end of year
Pool Payments
Key elements of pooling:
Sharing of risks, expenses & revenues
Payment of an average price
Possible adjustments for product quality, and for
time & location of delivery
Distributions of patronage refunds to specific pools for
members’ deliveries
Unique to ag marketing cooperatives
Used extensively by fruit, vegetable, nut, rice & dairy
cooperatives
Co-op can have single or multiple pools
Operating Procedures for
Pooling
Producers sign marketing contracts for their
crops—often with an “exclusive” clause
Contracts transfers all authority over marketing
decisions from producer to co-op
Initial advance payment to producer upon
delivery of product
When most or all product sold, close pool;
Determine total value, including estimated value
of remaining inventory
Operating Procedures for
Pooling (Cont.)
Operating, processing & administrative
expenses are allocated & deducted
Any excess over previous payments is then
distributed to members
Capital retain is withheld
Cooperative Taxation:
Single Taxation
Co-ops use a single tax principle
Either the co-op or patron pays the tax, usually
not both
Treatment is similar to partnerships, LLCs
In contrast, IOF corporations are taxed
twice
First at the corporate level, and again by
stock holders on dividends (or capital gains)
IRS uses the “Pass Through” taxation
theory
It assumes the co-op is an extension of the
members’ businesses—farm, ranch, hardware
store, grocery store, etc.
Cooperative Taxation:
Sub-Chapter T
Sub-Chapter T of the Internal Revenue Code
applies to “any corporation operating on a
cooperative basis”
Sub- Chapter T allows normal business deductions
and certain patronage refunds & per-unit retains
to reduce the co-op’s taxable income
Qualifying for Subchapter T
Requires “Operating on a cooperative
basis” :
Subordination of capital
Democratic control
Earnings shared on patronage basis
Additional requirements:
Treat all patrons alike
50%+ of business done with members
Subchapter C Firm Tax Illustration
Pre-tax Net Income $1,000,000
Corporation Tax @ 40% (400,000)
After-tax Net Income 600,000
Dividend 600,000
Personal Tax @ 34% 204,000
Net Net to Shareholders 396,000
Cooperative Tax Illustration
Pre-tax Net Income $1,000,000
Patronage (1,000,000)
Taxable Income 0
Patronage Refund 1,000,000
Personal Tax @ 34% 340,000
Net Net to Members 660,000
Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part I
Longstanding debate if tax treatment is
unfair as other corporations are subject to
double-taxation
Traditional defense:
Stresses non-profit character
Patronage earnings are not profit
distributions but merely year end price
adjustments
Subchapter T tax treatment is fair and consistent
with the rest of the tax code
Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part I
Comparison to corporate taxes needs to consider
special deductions
Exceptions for capital gains
60% of long-term not offset by losses excluded
from taxable income
Exclusions for dividends received
Exclude up to 85% of dividends received
Comparison to S corporations (Sole proprietorship, and
partnerships) rather than operation at cost argument
(corporate taxes as exception rather than norm)
Comparison to vertically integrated corporations
Internal transactions (Patronage) are not taxed
Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part II
Has the cooperative tax advantage been
harmful to the economy?
1)Has cooperatives’ market power shown an
alarming rate of increase?
2)Do co-ops that have a large market share
use their size to harm consumers and the
economy? Could they if they wanted to?
There is no basis to the contention that co-
op’s tax treatment has or will be harmful to
the economy.
Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part II
Statistical evidence does not indicate pattern of
market power
Market share of 4 largest cooperatives modest
(and smaller than percent of four largest non-
cooperatives in Agricultural supply, and other
industries)
Not supported by data (other than federally
supported marketing orders)
Many procompetitive effects (e.g. forming
cooperative when they face monopoly, or
when no for-profit will serve the market)
Market Concentration For
Agricultural Input Industries (Fuglie
et al 2012, and ETC group 2013)
Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part II
Statistical evidence does not indicate pattern of
market power
Restricting membership and controlling output not
supported by data (with exceptions, e.g. Blue
Diamond, federally supported marketing orders)
Limited evidence of price discrimination
Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part II
Statistical evidence does not indicate pattern of
market power
Restricting membership and controlling output
not supported by data (with exceptions, e.g.
federally supported marketing orders)
Limited evidence of price discrimination
Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part II
Statistical evidence does not indicate
pattern of market power
Farmers form cooperatives when
they face market power or no for
profit-enterprise will service the
market
Summary: Taxes
Subchapter T applies to any type of co-op; it
enables co-ops to practice “pass through” income
As public policy, Subchapter T provides favorable
treatment of co-ops (as compared to
corporations), Tax rules reinforce co-op principles
Tax treatment is fair and consistent with tax code
Tax advantage contributed to cooperative growth,
but not at expense of the economy overall
- ARE 132: COOPERATIVE BUSINESS ENTERPRISES�
- Allocation of Losses
- Co-op Member Payment Methods
- Co-op Member Payment Method: $ on Delivery
- Commercial Market Value (CMV)
- Back to Economic Theory
- Commercial Market Value (CMV) (Cont.)
- Key Concepts: Marketing Margin
- 1. Margin Reduction
- 2. Market Power Avoidance
- 3. Influence Consumer Prices
- Marginalization
- Slide Number 13
- Marketing Year
- Pool Payments
- Operating Procedures for Pooling
- Operating Procedures for Pooling (Cont.)
- Cooperative Taxation:�Single Taxation
- Cooperative Taxation:�Sub-Chapter T
- Qualifying for Subchapter T
- Subchapter C Firm Tax Illustration
- Cooperative Tax Illustration
- Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part I
- Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part I
- Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part II
- Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part II
- Market Concentration For Agricultural Input Industries (Fuglie et al 2012, and ETC group 2013)
- Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part II
- Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part II
- Sexton an Sexton (1986): Part II
- Summary: Taxes